48 pages • 1 hour read
A modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.
Summary
Background
Chapter Summaries & Analyses
Key Figures
Themes
Index of Terms
Important Quotes
Essay Topics
Tools
Paine mocks Burke’s insistence that wisdom follows hereditary government. Paine predicts that the new governments in America and France will last for at least a thousand years; he further predicts that no counter-revolution could ever come to France. He denounces as despotic Burke’s claim that in England, the king occupies his throne independent of the will of the people. Where Burke attempts to minimize the role of the people in the making of their own government, Paine responds by diminishing the British monarchy, referring to the ruling “House of Brunswick”—also called the House of Hanover—as “one of the petty tribes of Germany” (73, emphasis added). In calling the royal family a “petty tribe” from “Germany,” Paine suggests that there is nothing inherently special about the family while also implying they are not exactly British, either. Whereas Burke regards hereditary monarchy as the key to British liberty, Paine equates hereditary monarchy with despotism, denouncing a system wherein a small part of the people chose the family that enjoy hereditary succession to the throne.
Paine then questions the value of monarchy as a government system, which, he observes, has lost its luster in America and France. Paine remarks that only those who are personally enriched by monarchy, such as aristocrats and holders of tax-supported pensions and useless government offices, seem to support it. Paine also notes that the more localized parts of the British government function on principles of self-government while the monarchy operates on German principles of despotism.
Paine then devotes several pages to the recent crisis involving King George III’s mental health crisis and subsequent incapacity. Prime Minister William Pitt, amongst others, argued that only Parliament could choose the king’s acting successor, or Regent. Paine answers this assertion by saying that since Parliament contains a hereditary House of Lords, it is even further removed from the true will of the people. He adds that sovereignty does not reside in the House of Commons either, which, though partially elective, is merely a partial agent of the sovereign people’s will.
Paine insists that Britain’s unwritten constitution is no constitution at all. He argues that the British constitution is little more than a prop for the government’s funding system of perpetual debt and taxation. In an elaborate explanation that occupies more space than any other subject in this chapter, Paine cites a recent report from a French finance minister to prove, based on annual importations from South America dating back more than 70 years, that the British possess far less gold and silver coin than they should, which explains why their rapacious government operates on credit and imposes onerous taxes on its people.
Paine then notes that the people of France finally took possession of their government when they decided to withhold the taxes it demanded. Paine predicts that the Revolution and the National Assembly are in the process of placing France on sound economic footing. Finally, Paine concludes by suggesting that Burke could only have objected to any of these developments in France because Burke himself is a courtier whose interests are aligned with the royal government he serves, and thus, all courtiers fear the French Revolution.
After devoting so much space in Part 1 to the narrative of the French Revolution, Paine henceforth focuses on Britain and the British government. This Miscellaneous Chapter makes arguments that refer back to points raised earlier in Part 1, while at the same time laying the groundwork for new and more elaborate arguments to come in Part 2.
Paine suggests that the “opinions of men with respect to government, are changing fast in all countries” (72). He claims this is especially true in America and France, where monarchy, aristocracy, and all hereditary authority are increasingly dismissed. Paine makes a similar argument earlier in Part 1, where he describes the impact of changing public opinion with regard to aristocratic titles: “If a whole country is disposed to hold them [the aristocracy] in contempt, all their value is gone, and none will own them” (41). Throughout the book, Paine both denounces and mocks monarchy because he believes that the system itself is fundamentally corrupt and flawed. Paine stresses the evils of hereditary government so that its form can be changed and a new government can be established on better principles—Paine understands that if ordinary people come to regard hierarchical distinctions and privileges as ridiculous, then those things will cease to exist. In his discussion of the Regency crisis, Paine makes a similar appeal to the will of the sovereign people, which he believes the present Parliament does not and cannot reflect due to its hierarchical nature (in particular, the House of Lords) and limited use as a representative body for the common British subject.
One of the most important arguments in Paine’s book is also perhaps the most obscure to modern readers: the 18th-century view and history of corruption in the British government. Early in this chapter, Paine mentions the House of Brunswick, more commonly known as the House of Hanover. Later, Paine describes “a band of interested men” (78). In the chapter’s final paragraph, he refers to “that creature known in all countries, and a friend to none, a COURTIER” (88) and even accuses Burke of being such a creature. All of these terms and references are connected.
In 1714, George I ascended to the British throne. The new king hailed from the German electorate of Hanover, then part of the Holy Roman Empire, and spoke no English. Since George I had little interest in British affairs, real power fell to the prime minister, a brand-new office in the early 1720s. The prime minister operated in Parliament, securing funding for the king’s foreign wars while at the same time securing his own position. The national debt exploded, heavy taxes were imposed upon the people, and the minister used the revenue to expand the size of the British government and fill government offices with his political allies and dependants. This is the “band of interested men” who grew rich on war and taxes. The term “courtier” refers to anyone who serves within the royal court.
Paine therefore makes all of these connections explicit: The corruption of the British government has a traceable history, is perpetuated by its hereditary features, and is responsible for the impoverishment of the British people. Those who defend the monarchical system—like Burke—have an invested interest in its continuation, and therefore, Paine suggests, they defend it not out of genuine political belief but out of personal self-interest.
Plus, gain access to 8,800+ more expert-written Study Guides.
Including features:
By Thomas Paine
Books on Justice & Injustice
View Collection
Books on U.S. History
View Collection
Challenging Authority
View Collection
Class
View Collection
Class
View Collection
European History
View Collection
Nation & Nationalism
View Collection
Philosophy, Logic, & Ethics
View Collection
Politics & Government
View Collection
Power
View Collection